Russell Mokhiber
and Robert Weissman
"Just between you and me, shouldn’t the World Bank be encouraging more
migration of the dirty industries to the LDCs [least developed
countries]?"
So wrote Treasury Secretary-designee Lawrence Summers, then the chief
economist at the World Bank, in a 1991 World Bank internal memorandum arguing
for the transfer of waste and dirty industries from industrialized to
developing countries.
There’s more: "I think the economic logic behind dumping a load of
toxic waste in the lowest wage country is impeccable and we should face up to
that. … I’ve always thought that underpopulated countries in Africa are
vastly underpolluted; their air quality is vastly inefficiently low compared
to Los Angeles or Mexico City."
After the memo was leaked, Summers apologized, saying it was intended to be
ironic and that it was offered as a thought experiment. Later reports suggest
that someone else actually wrote the memo, although Summers’ name appeared on
it.
But here is the question that remains unanswered, and that should be atop
the list of questions posed by the senators who have to confirm Summers’
appointment to replace outgoing Treasury Secretary Robert Rubin: "Ironic
or not, from your point of view, what was wrong with the logic of the
memo?"
The notion that poor countries should import pollution and waste is just an
unsavory application of the economic theory of the U.S. Treasury Department,
shared also by the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and, to a lesser extent,
the World Bank. In this worldview, poor countries should exploit their
"comparative advantage" of low wages, or access to natural
resources, or lower environmental standards.
While few countries have "developed" with this approach, it has
proved very effective for companies like Nike, which has taken advantage of
low wages throughout Asia, or even GM, which produces cars and trucks in
Mexico with the same technology as in Michigan but with lower-wage workers.
Makers of polluting technologies such as incinerators that are being phased
out in industrialized countries have also benefited, because they are able to
stay in business by selling to Third World countries. U.S. manufacturers that
wanted to escape environmental regulations (like furniture makers who use
toxic glues, solvents and paints) have capitalized by shifting from places
like Los Angeles to Mexico. For a time, per Summers’ suggestion, there was a
thriving international trade in toxic waste, but that has largely been
eradicated, thanks to environmental activists who helped get enacted a global
treaty to ban hazardous waste exports from rich to poor countries (the United
States has not signed).
At the heart of the Treasury-IMF-Bank approach is the idea that developing
countries should concentrate their effort on exports, rather than production
for local needs. A related core idea is that countries should allow foreign
capital to move into and out of the country without restraint. Those two
policy prescriptions contributed in significant measure to the Asian economic
crisis, which was precipitated by a sudden withdrawal of foreign capital from
Asian markets, itself a result in part of over-investment in production for
export.
The solution of Summers, Rubin and Federal Reserve Chair Alan Greenspan
(anointed the "Committee to Save the World" by Time Magazine) was
for Asian countries to do more of the same (while making some internal
financial reforms and shutting down or selling off bankrupt enterprises).
Again, multinational corporations and foreign investors are doing well. U.S.
firms like Fairchild Semiconductors, Hartford Life and GE Capital, for
example, have made unprecedented purchases of Korean assets.
The overall result of the Committee’s global financial crisis management,
according to most news accounts including the many beatifying Rubin following
his retirement announcement, has been a steadying of the economic crisis. In
fact, while stock prices are now rising in the Asian countries, so is
unemployment and poverty.
Unemployment in South Korea rose from a tiny 2.6 percent to more than 8
percent and climbing. More is coming, according to IMF projections.
Indonesia’s economy shrunk by 15 percent in 1998. More than a half million
Indonesian children have died from malnutrition since the crisis began. The
country’s poverty rate has soared to at least 40 percent.
There is, too, massive environmental destruction stemming from the crisis
— a bleak fulfillment of sorts of the Summers memo’s prescription. In
Thailand, for example, devaluation and the export emphasis has led to more
agricultural exports and the expansion of shrimp farming, which the Asian
Development Bank says is causing "destruction of wetlands and increased
salinity of rice lands." Illegal logging is leading to further erosion
and deforestation.
The trouble with Larry Summers and his memo is not that it was an
aberration stemming from a lapse of good judgment. The trouble is that it
wasn’t.
Russell Mokhiber is editor of the Washington, D.C.-based Corporate Crime
Reporter. Robert Weissman is editor of the Washington, D.C.-based
Multinational Monitor. They are co-authors of Corporate Predators: The Hunt
for MegaProfits and the Attack on Democracy (Common Courage Press, 1999; see
http://www.corporatepredators.org).