Looking Forward. By Michael Albert and Robin Hahnel

 Go to Table of Contents

 

  9. Allocation Decision Making

 

 

 

Who or what institution, except at the centre, can consider the needs of the whole society? What local authority or committee could do so, when it could only have knowledge and responsibility for its own locality? How could the production unit know for whom to produce, what to produce, when to supply it, how it is to obtain its inputs (and from where) unless the planners decide and inform?

 

-Alec Nove

 

 

Having seen how participatory planning works from the perspective of individual production and consumption units, we now address the planning procedure as a whole.

 

Developing Initial Data

 

In earlier chapters we assumed long-run projects were decided before annual planning, and that at the outset of the yearly planning process each economic actor had access to important information. How is this accomplished?

 

Long-Run Plans

 

Should society make a qualitative change in coal mining that drastically improves health and safety, update existing steel plants, build anew high-speed rail line, or transform agriculture to conform to ecological norms? All may be desirable, but presumably given limited resources, not all can be done at the same time. That is the meaning of long-term investment choice and is the problem it -3oses. Which projects are worth doing and which are not? What order should they be done in? And how fast should we tackle the list, which is to say, how much present consumption are we willing to sacrifice for future benefit?

 

Long- and short-run investment projects differ in regard to how many years' resources must be committed for the project to reach fruition. Large- and small-scale investment projects differ regarding the magnitude of commitments and the breadth of efforts required. One approach to long-run planning would be to handle this issue before yearly planning begins. At this time, all previously agreed-to long-run projects could be reviewed and updated so that the commitment of resources necessary for this year could become part of subsequent planning calculations. After national projects, large regions could settle on their new long-run projects, and so on, down to the smallest units. In each case, alternative proposals could be aired, preferences expressed, implications assessed, new alternatives broached, options eliminated and improved, and final decisions made, all by participatory procedures similar to those described in our discussion of county-wide planning in chapter 8.

 

A procedure that could shorten the process would be to first decide the proportion of economic resources we want to commit to investment. Debate about options could then be made knowing roughly how much productive resources were available. Formulation, presentation, and modification of long-run investment options could be made and updated by the investment facilitation boards, who could base their proposals on polls and submissions from units, as outlined in the county example in chapter 8.

 

It is important to recognize the advantages of collective, participatory, investment planning. In capitalist or market coordinator economies each unit assesses potential investments according to norms imposed by the market and class system. In the workplace, the decision to switch from one technology to another is made by assessing likely profit/loss and capital/labor or coordinator/labor bargaining implications. But this is most definitely not deciding on the basis of social cost and social benefit. Only the benefit of the owner and stockholders is accounted for. Moreover, investment decisions in market economies are not even planned in coordination with one another. For example, the steel plant that decides not to introduce new technology because it appears unprofitable might have decided differently were they able to foresee how innovations in other industries would dramatically alter the cost of inputs or demand for steel.

 

In participatory planning, on the other hand, coordinated planning in light of social costs and benefits is possible. Each potential investment stands or falls not because of contemporary relationships alone, but because of conditions most likely to prevail once all innovations come on line. Whatever criteria society adopts to determine whether to enact particular investments, the participatory planning system will produce a more accurate assessment of social costs and benefits than would capitalist or coordinator systems. In addition, in a participatory system judgments will emphasize the impact of choices on the whole economy's productivity and social elations from the point of view of improving the quality of life of all workers and consumers, rather than just the circumstances of elite classes.