Looking Forward. By Michael Albert and Robin Hahnel

 Go to Table of Contents

 

  6. Participatory Allocation

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

"Moreover, when we consider that each product's status affects the status of many others, so that during an iteration changes in eating out at restaurants will affect the status of gas for cars and food for home cooking, we can see just how messy things might become."

 

 

 

 

 

 

 




 

 

 Is it possible to move such substantial amounts of information to so many different nodes? Consider that we are talking about moving electronic information. The U.S. postal system has the much harder task of moving physical packages. In fact, in 1987 the federal postal service had nearly 840,000 employees moving roughly 160 billion pieces of mail (about 656 pieces per capita). To accomplish this there are a little over 40,000 post offices, stations, branches, and so on. Obviously a much smaller apparatus would suffice for participatory planning's communicative infrastructure­ - perhaps something about the size of United Parcel Services, operating a communications process more like a computer information service.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

"You suggest some level of work effort for yourself and, implicitly, an average for everyone, and some level of consumption for yourself and, again, implicitly, an average for everyone. To be realistic you make these proposals compatible."

 




 

Converging

 

A little thought reveals there is no reason to expect a totally unguided sequence of participatory planning iterations to necessarily converge. For example, one product that begins in excess demand could flip into excess supply in the next iteration as workers offer to produce more and consumers to request less, and this flip-flop could continue from round to round. Alternatively, a good's status might not reverse every time but might follow a crazy path that never converges toward equilibrium. Moreover, when we consider that each product's status affects the status of many others, so that during an iteration changes in eating out at restaurants will affect the status of gas for cars and food for home cooking, we can see just how messy things might become. Just as we make progress on one front, another could get farther out of whack. Economists conveniently deploy simplifying assumptions to make these problems go away in their economic models-must notably what they call "convexity" and "gross substitutability" assumptions. But the only way to make these problems "go away" in the real world is to implement flexible rules and deploy experienced lFBs to help guide the process. Clearly, we need to adopt rules and authorize interventions that do not bias outcomes or reduce efficiency or equity unduly but that do ensure that convergence occurs in a reasonable time.

 

We should emphasize again that there is no one correct way to operate a participatory planning system. Many features are contingent. The various tasks we have enumerated could surely be carried out in different ways. Facilitation boards could be defined differently or even replaced by other institutions. Moreover, in real societies, economies exist in social contexts co-determined by kinship relations, governing forms, and cultural relations (as discussed further in our concluding chapter). There is no reason to 'expect that participatory structures will be identical despite differences in these other spheres of social life. Thus, developing preferred rules and institutions will be largely a historical task. Chosen forms in any particular society will have to fit particular environmental, historical, and cultural circumstances that no abstract model such as ours can fully anticipate, and, in any event, the character of optimal institutions and rules Will alter as any particular participatory economy develops. It may even be that within one economy different but compatible rule systems will operate in different areas, reflecting differences in climate, resources, or culture. Here, therefore, we only describe one workable approach for getting the "bargaining process" to converge to a desirable economic plan. Even the simple approach we highlight, however, suffices to demonstrate the viability of participatory planning and illustrate the kinds of calculations and decisions essential to its operation.

 

The first step in our example planning process is for each individual to think about his or her plan for the year. We can save some mental energy by considering someone who is intending not to save or borrow, since savers and borrowers function identically after appropriate adjustments. Everyone works at balanced job complexes and everyone receives an updated calculation of projected averages for production and consumption before each iteration. The iteration facilitation boards (lFBs) use knowledge of last year's plan, productive investments, changes in the labor force, and estimates of necessary "slack" to predict total output and translate this into average consumption and work loads. Each individual thus has an idea of what a fair consumption request and fair work proposal would be.

 

Now consider making a first proposal. You suggest some level of work effort for yourself and, implicitly, an average for everyone, and some level of consumption for yourself and, again, implicitly, an average for everyone. To be realistic-after taking into account what may be your above average needs-you make these proposals compatible. Therefore, what you really propose is: "I would like to work such and such an amount at my job complex and to consume such and such a total, broken into the following particular items. My work total and consumption total generally accord with each other and assume such and such an average consumption and production for society." Everyone makes a similar proposal in light of their particular preferences and capabilities but recognizing that the overall amount consumed must be produced, and that the distribution of burdens and benefits should be equitable..

 

Note that it wouldn't even be possible to actually enact everyone's first production proposals, since in most workplaces one person in a team may have proposed working more hours than another person in the same team, even though they can only work together. The plant's first production proposal used for lFBs calculations of new indicative prices, must therefore be calculated as an abstracted average of all its workers' separate proposals. In any event, after first proposals are summed and the results tabulated and summarized the second iteration can proceed.

 

According to the rule system in this example economy, everyone would still act individually. You compare your proposed work load and proposed consumption with the average of others' proposals. You also consider more localized averages, for example in your workplace, industry, complex, or neighborhood. You consider the status of each item you ordered and consult explanations of what seemed to be oddities such as large changes in worker productivity or consumer requests. Finally, you consult the new list of indicative prices adjusted according to relative excess demands and supplies in first round proposals. Then you make any changes you wish before entering your second proposal.